In the middle of a committee mark up session for a major spending
bill, one Senator was moved to observe, “A billion here, a billion
there … after a while you're talking about real money.” Today,
it’s a trillion here, a trillion there adding up to real budget
deceits and the National Debt.
I’d like to
discuss three things: what are we talking about, why does it matter,
and the political battle ahead.
A really important caveat: my area of expertise has always been international, not U.S. politics, so this piece should be taken with more than the usual grain of salt.
A really important caveat: my area of expertise has always been international, not U.S. politics, so this piece should be taken with more than the usual grain of salt.
Federal
Deficits and National Debt
The Deficit
Most years the
Federal government runs a budget deficit because it spends more money
than it raises in taxes and fees. There are two main forces driving
budget deficits: the politics of taxing and spending and deliberate
policy. In an annual ritual of “let’s pretend” the President
submits a proposed national budget to Congress. The White House
pretends that this is a realistic and thoughtful proposal and
Congress pretends that it will take it seriously. In fact the
President's budget proposal is deliberately unrealistic, designed to
appeal to the base. Members of Congress know that the real budget
will come out of an array of House and Senate committees that
individually and collectively will make decisions about spending and
taxes.
Despite repeated
efforts to reform and rationalize the process, the Congressional
system for developing a budget is decentralized and piecemeal, with
individual committees working through different sections of the
budget and not surprisingly, hearing from lobbyists, interest groups,
representatives of Executive branch departments, and people dependent
on various programs who want to make sure their particular program is
funded. Meanwhile other committees are responsible for tax policy,
with lots of helpful advice from those who want to make sure their
favorite part of the tax code is protected, and a different committee
is ultimately responsible for reconciling all these disparate pieces
into a package that can be passed by the House and by the Senate.
The second major
factor driving deficits is “counter-cyclical spending” – the
idea that the Federal government should increase spending or cut
taxes, even as revenue declines, during economic downturns. The
current series of Coronavirus relief bills is the perfect example.
The second half of the counter-cyclical theory – raise taxes and/or
cut spending when times are good is a lot harder to implement.
The 2017 tax cuts
had already created a major deficit before the Coronavirus hit.* So
far about $3 trillion has been spent on emergency relief and Congress
is working on another bill that could easily run to another trillion
dollars in debt.
*The tax cuts were
justified by the promise that they would cause the economy to grow by
at least 3% a year and thus pay for themselves in increased revenue.
Growth has been well less than that in all but one quarter since
then.
The National
Debt
The government
sells bonds to finance the debt. U.S. bonds are attractive
investments for foreign governments and extremely wealthy investors
because they are super safe and a source of dollars. Once upon a
time governments stored their national treasure as gold. But gold is
expensive to store, of limited use in international trade, and just
sits there in the vault. U.S. bonds don’t require fortified vaults
to store, the dollar is the foundation of global trade, and bonds get
you interest payments in U.S. dollars. And government bonds are
secure; the United States is not going to default on interest
payments or devalue the dollar and wipe out your national treasury.
So
What?
The budget
deficit tends to stimulate the economy and encourage growth
because it means more money out into the hands of consumers. It also
means the government is competing with other investors in the bond
market and tends to drive up interest rates. Too much deficit leads
to inflation; too little deficit can slow the economy by decreasing
demand and reducing the money supply. The role of Federal Reserve is
to try to regulate interest rates to compensate for the effects of
too much or to little deficit spending.
In the short term
National Debt matters because paying interest on the bonds
that finance it takes a large bite out of the Federal budget, money
that could be better spent on infrastructure or expanding health care
or reducing taxes.
In the longer
term, the size of the Debt impacts the relationship of the U.S.
economy to the rest of the world and the ability to maintain a strong
and growing economy.
A country's credit
rating is not based on the amount of debt but the ratio of debt to
Gross National Product. That has varied over the years: immediately
after World War II it was at 122%, in 1960 the National Debt was 53%
of GDP, in 1980 it dropped to 35%, in 2000 it was 58%.
But today’s 25
trillion (and counting) debt is 115% of the 22 trillion dollar U.S.
economy. If this were the situation in any other country in the
world alarm bells would be ringing in international financial circles
and the dollar would be plummeting like a stone. The fact that
neither of these things is true underscores how much the U.S.
benefits from the factor that global market runs on dollars. Because
the dollar is the basic currency for international transactions, the
U.S. is the largest economy in the world, and we have never defaulted
on a bond, we are uniquely able to sell bonds to finance our debt.
Other rich developed countries can finance their much smaller debt by
selling some bonds and borrowing from institutions like the European
Central Bank but usually must satisfy bond buyers or lenders that the
deficit is only temporary. Poorer countries have a hard time selling
their bonds and end up borrowing from international banks at high
interest rates or seeking help from the International Monetary Fund
which insists that governments adopt a program of reducing spending
and raising revenues before they can continue to get loans. Any
other country in the world with our pattern of deficit and debt would
be forced to impose an austerity program on its citizens, slashing
pensions and public spending and raising taxes.
As the global
economy expands and other countries catch up to the U.S.,
international investors and national governments have attractive
alternatives to U.S. bonds for their money and the U.S. will have to
pay higher and higher interest on its bonds. The interest rate on
government bonds affects the interest rates throughout the economy
and can simultaneously cause high inflation and retard growth. No one
can say for sure when, but if current trends continue, there will
come a day when interest on the Debt will become unsustainable. At
some point an out of control National Debt will create such high
inflation coupled with slow growth and absorb so much of the national
budget that other countries and international investors will decide
that U.S. bounds are not a good investment and we’ll be forced to
turn to the International Monetary fund for a loan to keep us going.
And then the United States will get the same treatment other global
debtors receive – posterity budgets that slash spending on domestic
programs, significantly higher taxes, and pressure to sell off
national assets to private investors.
The
Politics of Debt Reduction
Taxing and
spending are where the political rubber hits the road. Decisions
about the budget deficit and reducing the National Debt will be
driven by ideology, partisanship, interest groups, and individual
legislators’ beliefs about who deserves help from the government.
It can’t be done any other way: there is no “objective” or
scientific way of making decisions that rest on basic value
judgments.
National politics
will be dominated by the Covid-19 pandemic for the next few years. I
think the 2020 election will be a referendum on President Trump’s
handling of the pandemic. The necessity to maintain a reasonable
annual deficit and trim the National Debt will cast a long shadow
over all tax and spending questions for several years to come. The
economic challenges posed by the pandemic will require difficult and
painful measures. Most serious economists believe that it is sheer
magical thinking to expect the economy to suddenly rebound in the
next few months even if Covid were to miracuously disappear.
The politics of
coping with the situation are complicated by the current rampant
partisanship in Congress. In the past there have been some members
of Congress who were focused on governance as well as partisanship
and individual issues and could get together behind the scenes to
negotiate a compromise package. The fact that many had been in
Congress a long time and had established personal relationships
helped. That is not true in 2020.
The politics are
further complicated by the fact that the Senate and House are
controlled by different parties who have had very little interest in
cooperating and that fact that the White House does not have the
ability or inclination to play an active and effective leadership
role in developing and promoting legislative solutions.
But even if
control of the White House and/or the Senate and House changes after
November, the struggle to respond to the economic challenges facing
the Federal government and many state governments will be defined by
the clash of two frameworks. Democrats will stress the centrality of
increasing taxes to reduce the deficit and begin to pay down the
National Debt; Republicans will stress the importance of cutting
spending.
The Democrats will
propose tax increases that are the mirror image of President Trump’s
2017 package: skewed heavily toward the wealthy and large
corporations. They will vigorously resist proposals to reduce
spending on social programs aimed at the poor and middle class while
trying to eliminate “corporate welfare” programs and reduce
defense spending. The emphasis on raising revenue will get an assist
in 2025 when the provisions of the 2017 tax package that reduced
taxes for individuals expire unless there is a deliberate decision to
continue them.
The Republican
position will emphasize spending reductions everywhere except defense
and oppose tax increases. Republicans tend to be especially
skeptical of that part of domestic spending that offers benefits or
services to which a person is entitled based on age (Social Security,
Medicare), income (Medicaid, SNAP), or status (student loans,
disability income). Under the rubric of “entitlement reform”
Republicans have frequently sought to reduce benefits and restrict
enrollment on the grounds that these programs are spiraling out of
control. Cutting entitlements has usually depended on the strengthen
of the constituency supporting the program. SNAP (the successor to
food stamps), for example, has been vulnerable to cuts because it
does not have a large body of passionate defenders in Congress and
its recipients, largely low income women and their children, are not
a significant voting block. And it has been relatively easy to
maintain comparatively low payments to doctors and hospitals for
Medicaid because providers can either charge other patients more or
decline to accept any Medicaid patients. (Democrats are not immune
to the temptation to cut programs with high costs and no potent
organized constituency.)
Social Security
and Medicare are very large and growing entitlement programs that
have passionate Congressional supporters and their beneficiaries tend
to be very consistent voters who are extremely sensitive to threats
to their benefits. Given their size and impact on the budget, Social
Security and Medicare have been prime targets for “entitlement
reform” for years but their political foundations make them risky
targets for budget hawks. Social Security is funded by payroll taxes
that go into a specify fund within the Federal budget. It is easy to
see that at some point in the future, as Baby Boomers retire and the
U.S. population in general ages, that current levels of payroll tax
will not generate enough money to cover the benefits sent to seniors.
That leads to three possibilities. 1) raise the retirement age,
which was done in 1983, so that from 1983 to 2027 it would gradually
creep up from 65 to 67; 2) raise the payroll tax limit. When your
income reaches a particular level, $140,000 this year, you and your
employer stop paying 6.2% of your wages into Social Security.
Perhaps the most logical response, but likely to face strong
opposition from everyone making more than $140k and their employers;
3) reduce the monthly Social Security benefit and annual Medicare
benefits. The political calculation changes dramatically if you
leave benefits intact for people currently in the programs but reduce
them for future retirees, especially if the reductions are phased in
over a number of years. The expectation would be that future
retirees would not miss benefits they’ve never had.
The same budget
crunch of rapidly growing expenses and precipitously declining
revenue afflict state and local governments as well. Many state and
local budgets were already struggling with the twin impacts of
escalating unfunded pension costs and the lingering impact of the
2008 recession. The fact that the states hardest hit by both the
recession and the pandemic are politically blue, with large urban
populations and strong public employee unions and are typically
struggling with unfunded pension deficits makes Federal assistance a
highly partisan issue. Both President Trump and Senate majority
leader Mitch McConnell have been decidedly unsympathetic to their
problems and openly reluctant to support “bail out” packages.
When members of
Congress from both parties come to believe that the post-pandemic
world demands action on both the Federal deficit and National Debt
and that states and municipalities can’t just declare bankruptcy
and start over, there will be action at the national level.
How much will be
done and who will bear the burden will depend on the 2020 election
and changes in the political landscape and economy over the next few
years.
No comments:
Post a Comment